At& T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board, 525 U.S. 366 (1999)

Contents:
Author: Justice Souter

Show Summary

At&T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board, 525 U.S. 366 (1999)

JUSTICE SOUTER, concurring in part and dissenting in part.

I agree with the Court’s holding that the Federal Communications Commission has authority to implement and interpret the disputed provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, and that deference is due to the Commission’s reasonable interpretation under Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Natural Resources Defense Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837 (1984). I disagree with the Court’s holding that the Commission was unreasonable in its interpretation of 47 U.S.C. § 251(d)(2) (1994 ed., Supp. II), which requires it to consider whether competitors’ access to network elements owned by Local Exchange Companies (LECs) is "necessary" and whether failure to provide access to such elements would "impair" competitors’ ability to provide services. Ante at 392. Because I think that, under Chevron, the Commission reasonably interpreted its duty to consider necessity and impairment, I respectfully dissent from Part III-B of the Court’s opinion.

The statutory provision in question specifies that, in determining what network elements should be made available on an unbundled basis to potential competitors of the LECs, the Commission "shall consider" whether "access to such network elements as are proprietary in nature is necessary," § 251(d)(2)(A), and whether "the failure to provide access" to network elements "would impair the ability of the telecommunications carrier seeking access to provide the services that it seeks to offer," § 251(d)(2)(B). The Commission interpreted "necessary" to mean "prerequisite for competition," in the sense that, without access to certain proprietary network elements, competitors’ "ability to compete would be significantly impaired or thwarted." In re Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 282, 11 FCC Rcd 15,499, 15641-15642 (1996) (First Report & Order). On this basis, it decided to require access to such elements unless the incumbent LEC could prove both that the requested network element was proprietary, and that the requesting competitor could offer the same service through the use of another, nonproprietary element offered by the incumbent LEC. Id., 283 at 15642.

The Commission interpreted "impair" to mean "diminished in value," and explained that a potential competitor’s ability to offer services would diminish in value when the quality of those services would decline or their price rise, absent the element in question. Id., 285 at 15643. The Commission chose to apply this standard "by evaluating whether a carrier could offer a service using other unbundled elements within an incumbent LEC’s network," ibid., and decided that whenever it would be more expensive for a competitor to offer a service using other available network elements, or whenever the service offered using those other elements would be of lower quality, the LEC must offer the desired element to the competitor, ibid.

In practice, as the Court observes, ante at 389, the Commission’s interpretation will probably allow a competitor to obtain access to any network element that it wants; a competitor is unlikely in fact to want an element that would be economically unjustifiable, and a weak economic justification will do. Under Chevron, the only question before us is whether the Commission’s interpretation, obviously favorable to potential competitors, falls outside the bounds of reasonableness.

As a matter of textual justification, certainly, the Commission is not to be faulted. The words "necessary" and "impair" are ambiguous in being susceptible to a fairly wide range of meanings, and doubtless can carry the meanings the Commission identified. If I want to replace a light bulb, I would be within an ordinary and fair meaning of the word "necessary" to say that a stepladder is "necessary" to install the bulb, even though I could stand instead on a chair, a milk can, or eight volumes of Gibbon. I could just as easily say that the want of a ladder would "impair" my ability to install the bulb under the same circumstances. These examples use the concepts of necessity and impairment in what might be called their weak senses, but these are unquestionably still ordinary uses of the words.

Accordingly, the Court goes too far when it says that under "the ordinary and fair meaning" of "necessary" and "impair," ante at 389-390,

[a]n entrant whose anticipated annual profits from the proposed service are reduced from 100% of investment to 99% of investment . . . has not ipso facto been "impair[ed] . . . in its ability to provide the services it seeks to offer;" and it cannot realistically be said that the network element enabling it to raise profits to 100% is "necessary,"

ante at 390. A service is surely "necessary" to my business in an ordinary, weak sense of necessity when that service would allow me to realize more profits, and a business can be said to be "impaired" in delivery of services in an ordinary, weak sense of impairment when something stops the business from getting the profit it wants for those services.

Not every choice of meaning that falls within the bounds of textual ambiguity is necessarily reasonable, to be sure, but the Court’s appeal to broader statutory policy comes up short, in my judgment. The Court says, with some intuitive plausibility, that "the Act requires the FCC to apply some limiting standard, rationally related to the goals of the Act, which it has simply failed to do." Ante at 388. In the Court’s eyes, the trouble with the Commission’s interpretation is that it "allows entrants, rather than the Commission, to determine" necessity and impairment, ante at 389, and so the Court concludes that,

if Congress had wanted to give blanket access to incumbents’ networks on a basis as unrestricted as the scheme the Commission has come up with, it would not have included § 251(d)(2) in the statute at all.

Ante at 390.

The Court thus judges the reasonableness of the Commission’s rule for implementing § 251(d)(2) by asking how likely it is that Congress would have legislated at all if its point in adopting the criteria of necessity and impairment was to do no more than require economic rationality, and the Court answers that the Commission’s notion of the congressional objective in using the ambiguous language is just too modest to be reasonable. The persuasiveness of the Court’s answer to its question, however, rests on overlooking the very different question that the Commission was obviously answering when it adopted Rule 319. As the Court itself notes, ante at 388-389, the Commission explicitly addressed the consequences that would follow from requiring an entrant to satisfy the necessity and impairment criteria by showing that alternative facilities were unavailable at reasonable cost from anyone except the incumbent LEC. First Report & Order ¶ 283, 11 FCC Rcd at 15642. To require that kind of a showing, the Commission said, would encourage duplication of facilities and personnel, with obvious systemic costs. Ibid. The Commission, in other words, was approaching the task of giving reasonable interpretations to "necessary" and "impair" by asking whether Congress would have mandated economic inefficiency as a limit on the objective of encouraging competition through ease of market entry. The Commission concluded, without any apparent implausibility, that the answer was no, and proceeded to implement the necessity and impairment provisions in accordance with that answer.

Before we conclude that the Commission’s reading of the statute was unreasonable, therefore, we have to do more than simply ask whether Congress would probably have legislated the necessity and impairment criteria in their weak senses. We have to ask whether the Commission’s further question is an irrelevant one, and (if it is not) whether the Commission’s answer is reasonably defensible. If the question is sensible and the answer fair, Chevron deference surely requires us to respect the Commission’s conclusion. This is so regardless of whether the answer to the Commission’s question points in a different direction from the answer to the Court’s question; there is no apparent reason why deference to the agency should not extend to the agency’s choice in responding to mutually ill-fitting clues to congressional meaning. This, indeed, is surely a classic case for such deference, the statute here being infected not only with "ambiguity," but even "self-contradiction." Ante at 397. I would accordingly respect the Commission’s choice to give primacy to the question it chose.

1. I agree with the majority’s analysis of the unbundling and pick-and-choose rules, which were not challenged on jurisdictional grounds.

2. The Mann-Elkins Act provided, in relevant part, that

the provisions of this Act shall apply to . . . telegraph, telephone, and cable companies . . . engaged in sending messages from one State, Territory, or District of the United States, to any other State, Territory or District of the United States, or to any foreign country, who shall be considered and held to be common carriers within the meaning and purpose of this Act.

Act of June 18, 1910, ch. 309, § 7, 36 Stat. 544-545.

3. I agree with the majority, ante at 386, that respondents’ challenge to the FCC’s assertion that it has authority under 47 U.S.C. § 208 to consider complaints arising under the 1996 Act is not ripe for review. It appears to me, however, that the Court of Appeals conclusion that the FCC lacks such authority carries considerable force.

4. My conclusion applies with equal force to other FCC regulations that trump the state commissions’ responsibilities, including exemptions, suspensions, and modification, § 251(f); approval of agreements predating the Act, § 252(a); and preemption of state access regulations that are inconsistent with FCC dictates, § 251(d)(3).

Contents:

Related Resources

None available for this document.

Download Options


Title: At& T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board, 525 U.S. 366 (1999)

Select an option:

*Note: A download may not start for up to 60 seconds.

Email Options


Title: At& T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board, 525 U.S. 366 (1999)

Select an option:

Email addres:

*Note: It may take up to 60 seconds for for the email to be generated.

Chicago: Souter, "Souter, J., Concurring and Dissenting," At& T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board, 525 U.S. 366 (1999) in 525 U.S. 366 525 U.S. 398–525 U.S. 402. Original Sources, accessed May 28, 2023, http://www.originalsources.com/Document.aspx?DocID=HF2BXM7TAU2H9B6.

MLA: Souter. "Souter, J., Concurring and Dissenting." At& T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board, 525 U.S. 366 (1999), in 525 U.S. 366, pp. 525 U.S. 398–525 U.S. 402. Original Sources. 28 May. 2023. http://www.originalsources.com/Document.aspx?DocID=HF2BXM7TAU2H9B6.

Harvard: Souter, 'Souter, J., Concurring and Dissenting' in At& T Corp. v. Iowa Utilities Board, 525 U.S. 366 (1999). cited in 1999, 525 U.S. 366, pp.525 U.S. 398–525 U.S. 402. Original Sources, retrieved 28 May 2023, from http://www.originalsources.com/Document.aspx?DocID=HF2BXM7TAU2H9B6.